Controlling Interest
Do
ceilings always result in lower rates?
Can ceilings reduce the amount of available credit?
Do some borrowers tend to benefit from ceilings more than others?
No one wants to
pay more interest than is necessary when they use credit. Whether shopping for
mortgages, business loans, or auto loans, we usually are concerned about rates
and terms and want to make sure we do not pay too much for the use of someone
else's money. Just as in any other purchase, when we buy credit we want to pay
the lowest price possible.
In the past, the government often tried to ensure that we pay "a fair rate" of interest by implementing usury ceilings or limits on the rates that lenders can charge. During the 1980s there was a general trend toward eliminating or raising these limits as policy-makers reacted to the high inflation and record interest rates of the late 1970s. During the early 1990s, however, the trend reversed as some suggested that caps should be placed on credit card rates, which remained at historically high levels while other key interest rates declined significantly.
On the surface, capping interest rates seems to be perfectly logical. To protect people from paying interest rates that are perceived as "too high," the government can simply mandate that rates be kept below a certain level. However, interest rate ceilings can have unintended consequences. This publication examines these possible consequences by discussing the economic theory behind the arguments for and against usury ceilings.
Just Another Market
Laws designed to
prevent usury, or the taking of "excessive" interest, have long been
the subject of controversy. While advocates of usury ceilings claim that such
controls protect consumers from abusive lending practices and enable them to
obtain loans at reasonable rates, their critics argue that they work to
consumers' disadvantage by restricting credit flows and distorting financial
markets.
In economic theory, the credit market is viewed like any other market. There are buyers (borrowers) and sellers (lenders) of credit; the price of credit is the interest rate.
Who Gets Hurt and Who Gets
Credit?
Many of the
strategies lenders are likely to follow in a "credit crunch," such as
setting rigid loan terms, screening borrowers more rigorously, or increasing
non-interest fees and charges, tend to concentrate the impact of usury ceilings
on certain borrowers. For example, imposing more stringent loan terms such as
shorter maturities and higher minimum loan size reallocates credit toward those
who are able to afford larger down payments or larger monthly payments,
generally those with higher incomes. Basing lending decisions heavily on
individual characteristics, such as borrowing history or income, without the
flexibility of adding risk premiums, can ration credit away from new or
high-risk consumers who might be willing to pay higher-than-ceiling rates.
Finally, adding non-interest charges (such as higher fees) eliminates from the
market those for whom these extra costs are too great.
By encouraging these lending practices, usury ceilings may fail to give consumers the protection and benefits that they were intended to provide. That is, usury laws may actually reduce the amount of credit that is available to low income or inexperienced borrowers. Low-priced credit is not useful to those who cannot meet the requirements for obtaining it.
Thus, when lenders ration credit by some means other than price, first-time borrowers, small borrowers, low-income and high-risk borrowers are likely to find it more difficult to obtain credit. The most creditworthy borrowers, on the other hand, may obtain more credit than they would have at normal market interest rates.
Furthermore, when lenders institute non-interest charges such as fees to compensate for interest rate ceilings, they effectively raise the cost of credit for all successful borrowers. Therefore, while a ceiling may reduce the explicit price of credit (interest rate), it may not result in lower overall costs of borrowing even for those able to obtain loans. Additionally, non-interest charges make it more complicated for customers to comprehend the total cost of borrowing and more difficult to make well-informed credit decisions.
While these lending practices and their undesirable consequences may exist in the absence of interest rate ceilings, several studies on the effects of usury ceilings have established that loan terms do become less favorable to borrowers when usury ceilings become more restrictive.
Increased Competition and
Consumer Responsibility
A common argument
in favor of usury laws is that without them, borrowers would be forced to pay
exorbitant interest rates, or at least rates that are unreasonable in relation
to the cost of supplying credit.
According to economic theory, a competitive market is sufficient to prevent lenders from exercising power over pricing or earning more than a normal return. The price established in a competitive market reflects suppliers' costs of providing the given amount of that good. To be sure, removing a binding usury ceiling will result in higher interest rates. However, if credit markets are competitive, the resulting market rate of interest will not exceed lenders costs (including a fair return) of supplying credit. It is when competition is absent that consumers may face unreasonable interest rates. Thus, the consequences of not having usury ceilings depend importantly on the competitiveness of credit markets. Indeed, the absence of competition is the only reason for imposing a usury ceiling that can be justified by economic theory.
Some of the responsibility for ensuring a competitive marketplace must be placed on borrowers themselves, since knowledgeable, informed borrowers help to foster competition in credit markets. When consumers do not know or cannot compare rates being charged by various lenders, each lender has more freedom to charge any rate--fair or unfair. A high level of borrower awareness can create a natural protection from unreasonable interest rates, in lieu of the external constraint of a usury ceiling. 1
Economic theory suggests that interest rates are best determined by the marketplace rather than by legislative mandate. In the case of credit cards, however, some felt in the early 1990s that the market was not working as it should. Although most interest rates on consumer and business loans decreased significantly, credit card rates remained close to their highs of the early 1980s, seemingly impervious to market forces.
Credit Cards Are
No Different
The credit cards
that seemed to attract the most attention were the bank-issued
"universal" cards such as Visa and Mastercard. These cards are called
"universal" because of their wide acceptance at all types of
establishments in contrast to retailer-issued cards and travel and
entertainment cards. However, in the late 1980s and early 1990s, the
distinctions were starting to blur as bank credit cards faced competition from
new players, such as Sears, AT&T, and GM.
Prior to the 1970s, there were only a few bank credit cards in existence. Most were tied to a specific bank network and lacked the "universal" aspect we take for granted today. The rapid expansion of Bank of America's program (today's Visa) and the Interbank group's program (MasterCard) in the early 1970s established the foundation for today's industry.
From their earliest days, both card systems realized that a wide
customer base would be highly desirable. Because of the nature of the service
being extended, with issuing banks receiving only a very small percentage of
each purchase amount charged, the best way to cover costs would be through a
huge volume of customers and transactions. But widening the customer base
brought more and more people into the credit pool who otherwise would not have
qualified for cards. This increased risks to the banks and necessitated a
higher interest rate on unpaid balances.
The inflation of
the late 1970s and early 1980s also had an effect. Generally, any loan that is
extended to a consumer is paid back with dollars that are earned in the future.
Because of this, both borrowers and lenders include expected inflation in
setting the interest rate.
2 This is done so that the lender or
provider of the funds does not lose purchasing power as a result of making the
loan.
During the late
1970s and early 1980s, as inflation rates reached into the teens, the usury
ceilings established in many states became binding. As inflation rates
surpassed the legal maximum interest rates in many of these states, a few banks
chose to get out of the credit card business. Others relocated to those states
with higher usury ceilings or no ceilings at all. But as rates rose, another
important phenomenon became apparent: consumers use of credit cards proved to
be relatively inelastic--i.e., demand did not appear to decline as prices
(interest rates) rose. Inelastic demand is illustrated in the diagram below in
which the quantity of credit demanded changes by relatively small amounts as
represented by the nearly vertical slope DD compared to the size of the price
(interest rate) change.
During the late 1970s and early 1980s, even though the nominal rates
on credit cards rose, almost the same percentage of customers were carrying
balances. In essence, there was little or no change in the demand for credit.
Additionally, the dollar amount of the average balance being carried forward
and financed from month to month had actually almost doubled.
Thus, credit card
users proved to be relatively slow in responding to changes in the marketplace,
which were reflected in higher credit costs in the 1980s. With seemingly
inelastic demand for credit, higher prices did not affect the amount of credit
demanded as much as expected.
What Caused the Inelasticity
As discussed
previously, every transaction has a seller and a purchaser, a supply side and a
demand side. When credit is used, supply comes from the lender. Sellers want
prices to exceed their costs of production, which for credit card transactions
includes the costs banks must pay to secure funds to lend. There are additional
overhead and transaction costs as well. But, in the simplest textbook
treatment, the cost of funds to banks is estimated as the rate they are paying
depositors or to borrow funds in the open market (usually estimated at the
Treasury bill rate or the federal funds rate).
The risk factor
to the bank also affects the supply side. The fact that the loan represented by
cards is unsecured (not backed by any collateral) makes the loan risky. Unlike
mortgages and auto loans, the bank retains no lien against the property
purchased. When there is no threat of repossession, the loan is generally believed
to be at greater risk of default and loss. Because of this, a riskier loan
demands higher interest rates. Therefore, one would expect an unsecured credit
card loan to have a higher rate than a similar secured loan. Nevertheless,
rates for credit cards should change in line with the general level of interest
rates, even with a higher risk premium. Interestingly, most statistics indicate
that the level of default for credit cards has tended to fluctuate within a
fairly narrow range over time. Therefore, it appears there is little on the
supply side of the equation to explain why credit card rates stayed level while
other rates fell.
There are a
number of factors on the demand side which may explain the lack of elasticity
for credit card demand during the 1980s. One interesting factor was the
apparent "brand loyalty" of credit card customers during the period.
This was particularly interesting because studies indicate that Americans show
varying levels of brand loyalty to many products that they use. Credit cards
would seem to be an odd item to invoke brand loyalty, but surveys have shown
that only recently have large numbers of consumers begun to cancel the first
credit card they received (often very expensive) in favor of those with a lower
price (interest rate and/or annual fee).
This "brand
loyalty" may reflect, in part, how aggressively different institutions
pursued customers. Those financial institutions that advertised heavily for new
customers often had higher rates and less restrictive credit qualifications.
Institutions offering lower rates and with more restrictive qualifications
often were not as aggressive in seeking new cardholders.
A related aspect
of brand loyalty may be an affinity for cards issued by the "big
name" banks. In general, the credit itself is no different whether offered
by a large money-center bank or a small town independent bank, but consumers
may have the perception that having a card issued by a large bank is an
indication of creditworthiness.
There also
appears to have been a perception among consumers that obtaining a new card
would not result in sufficient savings. This would be true if the consumer is
in that portion (approximately one third) that pays the balance due, in full,
each month. Under those circumstances, and if the card carries no annual fee,
why worry about the interest rate?
Even some of
those who do carry a balance may not worry about the interest rate. Several
studies have noted that more consumers see themselves as convenience borrowers
(charging and paying off the entire balance monthly) than really exhibit such
behavior; one study showed almost twice as many. Thus some consumers may not be
concerned about interest rates even when they incur interest charges.
How Does One Define Competition?
Thus, there are
several alternative explanations for the "non-competitiveness" in
credit card rates ranging from brand loyalty to consumers' self-perception.
But, we need to examine competition itself. Many people think of competition
purely in terms of price, with one supplier lowering price to gain a market
advantage, and subsequently forcing other suppliers to do likewise or lose
market share. But another method of competing is to improve the quality of the
product: that is, to keep the price constant but to provide more to the
consumer.
If we follow this
line of reasoning, it is possible that credit cards are more competitive than
commonly believed. Early on, credit card issuers saw quality as a way to
provide more service to the customer without a substantial increase in costs.
Among features that were rapidly introduced as technology improved were cash
advances, which allowed customers to borrow cash without going through a formal
loan process--in essence, a personal credit line. The 1980s also saw a proliferation
of services attached to credit cards such as "buyer protection,"
which allowed for free replacement should an item purchased with the card be
defective or stolen; random refunds of credit card purchases; and cash bonuses
or other rebates on purchases of select products based on total purchases made
with the card.
These services
have added to the perceived quality of the product and all of them involve some
cost to the supplier. In cases in which these costs were not charged directly
to the customer, institutions chose to compete by improving quality as well as
by lowering price.
Evolution in the '90s
Why, then, did
credit card rates appear to remain high in the early 1990s rather than return
to the levels of the early 1970s? Part of the answer lies in the costs that are
inherent in providing credit cards, such as the high risk of unsecured loans.
But perhaps a more important factor was the credit card market itself. As we've
seen, demand for credit cards was relatively inelastic, with consumers less
responsive to interest rates than might have been expected. On the supply side,
ten issuing institutions accounted for more than half of the cards in the United
States at the end of the 1980s. Although it would be wrong to say that
the market did not work, it is appropriate to ask whether a market dominated by
a relatively small number of suppliers responding to inelastic demand by buyers
can be considered truly competitive.
However, that
situation began to change in the early 1990s. Consumers have become more aware
of credit card terms and rates and more willing to search for the best deal,
matching services to their needs. And, importantly, a host of new competitors
have entered the card field, greatly intensifying competition in terms of both
service and price. The "high" prices, whether actual or perceived,
attracted new sellers to the market. In short, the market worked the way it
usually has in the past, fostering increased competition and more selection for
consumers.
As competition
continues to increase within the credit card market, consumers will have more
choices. As consumers take advantage of their additional options, the market
will be better able to allocate credit via various forms of competition,
including price and service. There is something to be gained by understanding
that, despite their stated intentions to the contrary, consumers are likely to
run a balance and pay interest. Likewise, services and perks that are never
used have no value and do add costs. Consumers need to match the card to their
use and choose accordingly. As was stated earlier, a high level of borrower
awareness can create a natural protection from unreasonable interest rates, in
lieu of the external constraint of a usury ceiling. With increased awareness the
"invisible hand" of the marketplace can help to ensure that the
credit card market meets the needs of borrowers and lenders alike.
Information on Credit Card Rates
The Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System publishes an extensive listing of bank
credit card terms on a semi-annual basis in their on-line publication Shop: The Card You Pick Can Save
You Money. Information provided includes interest rates, annual fees (if
any), grace periods, geographic limitations, and other information pertinent to
making an informed consumer choice.
1
In an effort to
enhance the ability of consumers to compare interest rate charges and,
therefore, to discourage unfair lending practices, Congress enacted the Truth
in Lending Act in 1968. Unlike usury laws, Truth in Lending does not set
interest rate limits. Rather, it requires creditors to provide clear and
consistent information about loan terms so that consumers can easily
"shop" for the best price and avoid charges that are out of line.
2
See Points
of Interest, (PDF
7.74MB)
published by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, for more
information on how inflation is calculated into interest rates.
Ordering Information
This publication,
as well as other Federal Reserve materials on money and banking, the financial
system, the economy, consumer credit, and related topics, can be ordered
on-line using our on-line
order form, or by contacting our Publications
Department.
Controlling Interest is one of a series of essays adapted from articles in On Reserve, a newsletter for economic educators. On Reserve is published by the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.